Introductory Comments by
Ron Michener, Associate Professor
Department of Economics, University of Virginia
The following article, "The Colonial Currency, Prices, and Exchange Rates," was
written, and is being published, under
unusual circumstances. Its author, Leslie Brock, died in 1985. The manuscript version of
the article he left behind lacked the
polish, terseness, and careful footnoting usually found in first-rate historical research.
Nonetheless, the article represents the final
judgement of one of the few universally acknowledged experts on American colonial
currency, and it addresses matters of
current controversy. As such, it ought to be available to historians and economists.
Explaining the significance of the article requires placing it in the context of Brock's
life and work. Leslie Brock was born in
1903 in Pittsburgh and grew up in Waynesburg, Pennsylvania. After graduating from
Waynesburg College in the summer of
1928, he joined the faculty of the College, where he taught history, economics, and
government. In 1938 he married Frances
Sutherland. While teaching at Waynesburg, Brock completed a Ph.D. in history at the
University of Michigan, where he was
trained by such distinguished scholars as Verner W. Crane and Dwight L. Dumond. His
doctoral dissertation, The Currency of
the American Colonies, 1700-1764, remains to this day an undisputed classic. John McCusker
and Russell R. Menard, in
The Economy of British America, 1607-1789, describe it as one of two "basic treatises
on currency in early British America."
Joseph Ernst--the author of the second basic treatise--praised it as "the best
description and analysis of American paper money
practices for the period it covers."
In 1947, Brock joined the faculty of the College of Idaho as professor and chairman f the
department of history, where he
served until his retirement in 1969. In 1966, the college honored Brock by naming him as
the first holder of the colleges
Weyerhaeuser chair. Brock set high standards, both for himself and his students. He
originally had conceived his dissertation as
covering the entire period up to 1776. On his advisers recommendation, he stopped at 1764,
but immediately after receiving his
degree began work on extending the study to the Revolution. For the later period Brock
relied far more on original sources
than he had in his dissertation, and by the mid-1950's, he had completed a draft of the
sequel. Now, however, he felt it
necessary to return to the earlier period, to write a more accurate account based on
original sources. Describing these events in
a 1969 letter, he wrote that he had "spent perhaps three times as much time and labor
as I did on my dissertation. At the
beginning I never thought it would take half so long, but I can truthfully say, `I have
not been idle."
Brock continued working on the currency project after his retirement, putting most of his
effort into gathering the source
documents needed to write the comprehensive history he had in mind. In 1975, he
reluctantly permitted Arno Press to publish
his 1941 doctoral dissertation, writing in the preface that "Only the realization
that time may not be given me to finish [the
comprehensive history] induced me to publish the dissertation."
By the late 1970s, Brock's health began to fail as he fell prey to a degenerative nerve
disease that took away his ability first to
write, and then to walk. Completing a book that would surpass his dissertation now became
impossible. In the spring of 1977,
he told Stuart Bruchey of his plans to write an article instead. "Such an article
needs to be written to redeem the subject from
the misconceptions (as I conceive them) of Joseph Albert Ernst. Apart from Ernst, I have
developed some statistical data that
introduce a new dimension into the behavior of exchange rates in New York and
Pennsylvania, for example, in the period after
the mid-forties, as these rates are influenced by the fluctuations of the price of Spanish
silver in London."
Unfortunately, Brock's failing health made even the article an ambitious and perhaps
unrealistic undertaking. Under his
supervision, Brock's wife, Frances, took over the job of typing, calculating, and drafting
tables and figures. But despite their
best efforts, the draft manuscript bore the marks of the difficult circumstances under
which it was written. When the William
and Mary Quarterly rejected it in 1980, the authors deteriorating health forced Frances
and Leslie to abandon the project.
As to the essay itself, Brock, in his response to Ernst's Money and Politics, addressed a
controversy that was about to break
with full force. The controversy concerns how the quantity theory of money can be
reconciled with colonial experience (if at
all). Before Ernst's book, many historians and economists simply had assumed that colonial
price levels varied in proportion to
the quantity of paper money in circulation. While perhaps true in New England before 1750,
and in the Carolinas early in the
eighteenth century, Ernst correctly argued that these cases were exceptional. Colonial
currency usually held its value even when
its quantity increased by several hundred per cent. How could this be explained? Robert
Craig West made the point even more
emphatically by methodically correlating price indices and currency supplies in several
colonies; he found that in most colonies
there was no correlation whatsoever.
This touched off a vigorous controversy among economists. In a series of articles, Bruce
Smith took up the attack on the
quantity theory of money and argued that the colonial experience showed the over-riding
importance of fiscal policy in
determining the value of currency. Currency did not depreciate in colonies that, in
Smith's language, "backed their currency" by
faithfully collecting taxes and outstanding public loans. After reviewing the experience
of individual colonies, Smith concluded
that the absence of backing was the critical factor in explaining why some colonial
currencies depreciated, while others did not.
Wicker and Calomiris also contributed to the controversy, emphasizing, as Smith did, the
importance of fiscal policy.
I have argued that backing, in this sense of the word, did not play an important role, and
have defended the quantity theory.
Colonial currency was far from being the only component of the money supply. Specie coins
were an important, even
predominate, part of the money supply in some colonies, and there were important
substitutes for money as well. The custom of
rating specie coins in the colonies at a fixed value in colonial currency--a Spanish
dollar, for example, was 8s. in colonial New
York--linked the value of currency to the value of silver in international markets. So
long as silver circulated as a medium of
exchange, and specie coins maintained their fixed rating, the currency would not
depreciate. Paper money emissions would
increase the demand for goods, but this would result not in higher prices, but in the
export of specie. Only when the
disappearance of specie caused the fixed rating to break down would depreciation commence.
According to this explanation,
depreciation occurred in those colonies which issued so much paper money that they
displaced their stock of circulating specie.
Michael D. Bordo and Ivan A. Marcotte, and Bennett T. McCallum have participated in the
debate on this side of the issue.1
Brock also argued that the circulation of specie coins and their customary rating was the
key factor, although his position varies
in many particulars from that of these economists. The lively controversy on this topic at
this time makes Brock's manuscript of
particular interest.
Also, Brock's estimates of the quantity of currency outstanding in the colonies have
become the standard used by all historians
and economists. While some of the tables in the essay simply repeat material from his
dissertation, several are new: the
estimates of Pennsylvania currency in circulation 1750-1775; Virginia currency outstanding
1755-1774; and the implicit
estimates of New Jersey currency outstanding 1750-1774.2 The tables showing New England
and New York currency
outstanding include minor corrections and revisions.
Historians with a general interest in the subject should know that the paper published
here is only a small part of the material on
colonial currency Brock left behind. The draft chapters for the sequel to his
dissertation, picking up the story in 1764 and
carrying it to the Revolution, plus a very detailed history of the Massachusetts currency
during the 1730s, still exist, as do
Brock's research notes, an extensive collection of primary and secondary source material
relating to colonial currency. Perhaps
the most useful portion of the collection are the xerox and microfilm copies of original
documents collected by Brock from
around the country and from Great Britain. Professor Joseph Ernst has already made
substantial use of the collection for a
book in progress on the currency of colonial Massachusetts.3
Finally, I should explain what I have done, and not done, in preparing the manuscript for
publication. The original manuscript
contained typographical and transcription errors as well as some numbers and statements
that ought to have been footnoted but
were not. While I have tried to eliminate the first kind of error, and provide footnotes
where sources were self-evident, the
reader should understand that the manuscript is being published essentially "as
is." Most of the missing documentation can be
found in Brock's research notes; after examining these notes I know that the answer to
"where did this number come from?" is
often not an easy one. Brock did not rely always upon published data series. For example,
he merged his data on exchange
rates with the data in McCusker's Money and Exchange, and used these revised figures in
the paper. He also developed his
own estimates of population in the colonies, and figures on trade balances per capita are
generally deflated with his own
population estimates. I abandoned the idea of providing complete footnotes because of the
difficulty of finding, understanding,
and describing all the calculations. When I could locate Brock's worksheets, I checked the
numbers in the paper against those
in the worksheets, and corrected transcription errors upon discovery. After checking all
the money supply figures against the
worksheets they were based on I am fairly confident of their accuracy. I am most uncertain
about the trade statistics.
One portion of the paper, Table VII and Figure V, required revision because it is a
particularly important calculation. The table
and figure show the deviations of the exchange rate in Pennsylvania, New York, and
Massachusetts from a par of exchange
calculated using the market price of silver in London. Brock took his silver price data
from McCusker's Money and
Exchange. McCusker's prices, though, are for standard (sterling) silver bullion. Since the
silver coins circulating in British
America were Spanish, they were of a different alloy, and being coined, they might be of
more or less value than the equivalent
bullion. From Brock's letters, I know he was aware of these problems, but had no better
data. Recently, I discovered the
London price of pieces of eight (per ounce) in Castaing's The Course of Exchange, a
contemporary newspaper, and
constructed a table of the London price of silver based on these figures. The table is
published here for the first time. Knowing
Brock would have used these figures if they had been available, I felt it was appropriate
to redo the table. The difference in the
two price series is small, but important. Independent evidence suggests a peacetime cost
of shipping specie from the colonies to
London of about 6%.4 Using McCusker's data, it appears that specie points were regularly
violated, sometimes significantly.
Using the correct data, however, largely eliminates these violations.
The Colonial Currency, Prices, and Exchange
Rates
Leslie V. Brock
Professor Emeritus of History, College of Idaho
Volume Thirty-Four 1992
Essays in History
Published by the Corcoran Department of History at the University of Virginia.
That the exchanges will be lowered, and the price of Bullion raised, by an issue of . .
. paper [currency] to excess, is not only established as a principle by the most eminent
authorities upon commerce and finance; but its practical truth has been illustrated by the
history of almost every state in modern times which has used a paper currency; and in all
those countries, this principle has finally been resorted to by their statesman, as the
best criterion to judge by, whether such currency was or was not excessive.
"The Bullion Report," 18105
The experience of past times, both of war and peace, leads us to suppose, that the
exchange between Great Britain and foreign countries is not likely to remain for any long
period unfavorable to Great Britain. That the quantity of circulating paper must be
limited, in order to the due maintenance of its value, is a principle on which it is of
especial consequence to insist. . . .
It . . . appears, that "the coming and going of gold" does not . . .
"depend wholly on the balance of trade." It depends on the quantity of
circulating medium issued; or it depends, as I will allow, on the balance of trade, if
that balance is admitted to depend on the quantity of circulating medium issued.
To limit the total amount of paper issued, and to resort for this purpose, whenever the
temptation to borrow is strong, to some effectual principle of restriction; in no case,
however, materially to diminish the sum in circulation, but to let it vibrate only within
certain limits; to afford a slow and cautious extension of it, as the general trade of the
kingdom enlarges itself; . . . this seems to be the true policy . .
Henry Thornton, 18016
The utility of the quantity theory of money in explaining the behavior of colonial
prices and exchange rates has lately been called in question. Joseph Albert Ernst
acknowledges that the quantity theory provides a sufficient explanation in the case of
runaway inflation, but he denies that it provides an explanation in the case of general
price equilibrium. In such a case, he contends, the explanation is to be found in the
interplay of demand and supply within the framework of the balance of payments.7 To
contend that this is so is to admit that gravity operates when a man falls to his death
over a precipice, but to deny that it operates when a man falls from a curbstone and
breaks an arm. Ernst's explanation leaves in limbo much, perhaps most, of colonial
monetary history which fell between the extremes of runaway inflation, of more moderate
price disturbances, and of general price equilibrium, if, indeed, such a case can be
isolated.
Since a clear understanding of the nature of both the circulating specie and the paper
currency of the colonies is necessary to achieve an understanding of the problems involved
in the determination of prices and exchange rates, perhaps a few words concerning each may
not be amiss. There was no colonial coinage nor did the sterling coin of Great Britain
circulate in the colonies. Consequently, it was necessary for the colonies to amass a
supply of coin through the medium of trade.
The money metal of the eighteenth century was silver, not gold. The chief coin of the
colonies was the Spanish milled dollar (piece of eight), worth 4s. 6d. sterling. There
were supplementary gold coins in circulation: the Johannes of Portugal, which circulated
after 1722 and was worth 36s. sterling, and the Spanish Pistole, which was worth 12s.
2.8d. sterling, and had a substantial circulation in Virginia prior to the French and
Indian War. The silver was chiefly derived from the West Indies trade. It was a saying in
New England in the early eighteenth century that the "Fishery was then the NE Silver
Mine."8 The gold came in as a result of trade with the south of Europe. The colonies
retained the British monetary units: pounds, shillings, pence (1 = 20s.; 1s. = 12d.). The
foreign coins in circulation in the colonies had values placed upon them by the several
colonial legislatures. They did not, however, long circulate at their sterling values.
Either to retain their coin or to draw it from their neighbors, colonies raised the value
at which it circulated within their boundaries. An upper limit to these values was set by
the Proclamation of Queen Anne of 1704, which placed a maximum of six shillings on the
Spanish milled dollar. Gold coins, however, were not within the scope of the proclamation.
Throughout the colonial period, specie in the colonies tended to be in short supply.
Colonial paper currency, generally called bills of credit, was issued on two bases: on
the credit of the colony supported by tax funds, and on loan. Massachusetts in 1690 was
the first colony to issue bills on the credit of the colony, and South Carolina in 1712,
if the abortive attempt by Barbados in 1706 be neglected, was the first colony to put out
bills on loan.9 As the first method evolved it became customary to strike off the bills of
credit, declare them a legal tender in both public and private transactions, and pay them
out to the public creditors. At the time of issue, provision was usually made for calling
in the bills. For example, a tax would be levied for the five years next ensuing, from the
proceeds of which one-fifth of the bills were retired annually. The tax was made payable
in the bills; when the bills were paid into the treasury, they were burned. By the second
method, the legislature established a "loan office" and struck off a sum in
bills, likewise making them a legal tender. It was the duty of the commissioners of the
loan office to place the bills out on loan in limited sums on adequate security, which was
usually in the form of a mortgage on landed property. It was customary to require the
property to be of double the value of the loan. Interest on the loan was payable annually,
and, beginning immediately or after a period of years, the principal was repaid in equal
annual installments running over eight or ten years. When payments on the principal were
received, the bills were retired by burning. Such issues served three purposes: (1) in an
age when private banks were unknown they supplied individuals with the credit necessary
for acquiring and improving land; (2) interest payments contributed to the public revenue;
and (3) the bills, while outstanding, supplied a medium of exchange.
Perhaps it should be noted, for the matter is much misunderstood, that the bills were
not redeemable in specie. When paid into the treasury in taxes or to the commissioners of
the loan office in payments on the principal, at least at the end of the lending period,
the bills were destroyed. As long as the quantity of bills was not excessive, they
retained their value. It was only when the original issue was excessive, or when repeated
issues, as in time of war, greatly increased the circulation that the bills depreciated.
We are interested in the effect of currency issues upon the general price level. The
changes in the price of individual commodities in response to changes in supply and demand
or in the seasonal or cyclical movement of individual prices are not our primary concern.
The existing colonial price indices based upon the prices of a few commodities bought or
sold in foreign commerce are in no way indicative of the general price level.10 The
colonial prices of such commodities depend predominantly upon the conditions of supply and
demand in foreign markets and on the rate of exchange. Only as monetary factors influence
colonial demand or the rate of exchange do they exert an influence upon such prices.
Evidence of the effect of currency expansion upon the general price level must be sought
elsewhere than in the existing price indices.
The colonists imported their manufactured goods from Britain, payment for which had to
be made in sterling funds. The colonists gained control over sterling funds as the result
of their exports. In the Southern colonies trade between the colonies and Great Britain
was direct. A Virginia planter might export his tobacco to Britain, consigning it to a
commission merchant who would sell it and place the proceeds to the Virginia planters
account. The proceeds produced a fund of sterling money upon which the Virginia planter
might draw. Perhaps he accompanied the shipment of his tobacco with an order for goods.
His correspondent in Britain would buy the goods and debit his account for the cost. The
goods would then be shipped to the colony when the tobacco ships again returned to
Virginia. Here no more than a bookkeeping transaction was necessary. If, however, the
Virginia planter wished to transfer some of his balance with his London correspondent to
Virginia for use in the colony, he might draw a bill of exchange on his correspondent for,
say, 100 sterling. The bill was in the nature of an order to his correspondent to pay 100
sterling. The planter then sold the bill at the going rate of exchange to a fellow
Virginian who had need of sterling funds to pay an obligation in Britain. The purchaser
forwarded the bill to his creditor in Britain, who presented it to the correspondent of
the Virginia planter for acceptance--for the custom was to draw bills of exchange payable
thirty days after sight. If the correspondent accepted the bill, the creditor then held it
for thirty days, at the end of which time he presented it for payment. The rate at which
sterling bills were sold in the colonies was determined at any one time by the effective
supply of, and demand for, sterling bills.11 The basic question, however, concerning the
effect of currency issues upon exchange rates revolves around the effect of such issues
upon the demand for, or, to a lesser degree, the supply of, bills of exchange. In the case
of New England and the Middle colonies, where direct trade between the colonies and
Britain was at a minimum, it was necessary for the colonies to have recourse to a
roundabout trade to procure the necessary bills of exchange and specie to pay their
adverse balances with Britain.
Sustained Inflation: New England, 1702-1750
The outbreak of Queen Anne's War (1702-1713) led to ever-increasing issues of bills of
credit drawn on the credit of the colonies by Massachusetts and to the introduction of
bills of credit in Connecticut and New Hampshire in 1709 and in Rhode Island in 1710 to
help those colonies to finance their exertions in the war. The nature of trade in New
England was such that the bills of one colony were soon introduced into another and came
to pass current there. In this way, since the bills of one colony enjoyed a
"promiscuous circulation"12 in the other colonies, they came to suffer a common
depreciation. In 1709 the paper circulation of New England amounted to 69,364; when the
war ended in 1713 it had grown to 219,448. "It has been estimated that there were
200,000 of silver in circulation in New England in 1700. By 1713 this sum had been reduced
to 130,000, and by 1718 according to some statements, or by 1726 according to others,
there was none remaining."13 In 1700 silver passed current in New England at 7s. the
ounce. It continued at this figure until 1705 when the value of silver was raised to 8s.
the ounce. This increase was not the result of the emission of bills of credit, but rather
of the reduction of the silver content of the Spanish milled dollar through the paring of
the coin, an action that proceeded from a resolution of the merchants to receive silver at
8s. the ounce. At first the bills of credit circulated at parity with silver and
manifested no tendency to depreciate. Later, however, it was a different story.
As the issues of bills of credit put out to finance the war increased from year to
year, they created purchasing power. This added purchasing power increased demand. Part,
at least, of the increased demand was for English goods. When there was a sufficient
amount of silver in the colony to maintain a stable exchange rate, this increase in
purchasing power caused increased importations and larger unfavorable balances of trade,
which in turn increased the demand for silver to meet these adverse balances. The price of
silver and exchange rose together; as exchange rose, the price of English goods measured
in colonial currency likewise rose. The effect upon domestic prices of increases in
purchasing power arising from issues of bills of credit was more direct. Here the
increased purchasing power acted upon the market directly as receivers of the bills
entered the market and bid up prices. It was otherwise in the case of commodities produced
largely for export, here a rise in sterling exchange was soon translated into higher
prices for these commodities measured in colonial currency.14 The effect of the later
issues, however, upon the price of silver differed from that of the earlier ones. Before
1710 the sum outstanding in bills of credit bore a small proportion to the sum of silver
in circulation. In 1710 there was perhaps as much silver in circulation as there were
bills. As long as this was true, silver sufficient to make remittances to England came
into the hands of merchants in the ordinary course of trade. After 1710, however, the
situation altered. Bills were emitted in larger quantities. Moreover, the outflow of
silver accelerated, for these were years in which the balance of trade with England was
extremely unfavorable. As the demand for silver for making payments abroad grew and as the
supply of the metal within the colony dwindled and fewer and fewer silver coins cam into
the hands of the merchants in the ordinary course of trade, the merchants began to bid one
against the other for it in order to make remittances to England, and thus its price rose.
The existence of a stock of silver in a colony served to retard the rise in the price of
the metal even in the face of a substantial increase in the sum outstanding in bills of
credit. As soon, however, as the stock became scarce, the rise became more rapid. Then
only the silver that was imported in the course of trade with Southern Europe and the West
Indies became available for export.15
Peace brought problems no less severe than had the war. The occasion for issuing
sizable sums in bills of credit ended and whatever stimulus to business activity generated
by the constant emission of ever larger sums in bills disappeared. Moreover, retirement of
the bills of credit outstanding by the annual tax levied for that purpose added to the
complexities facing the New Englanders. In these factors--the end of wartime activity and
expenditures, and the prospect
It is not remarkable, therefore, that during the next year (1714) a cry of scarcity of
money was heard. A cry in which the commercial element in the province joined, for as
Cotton Mather, writing at the time, reported, the Gentlemen of Business of the province
considered the number and value of the bills of credit remaining in circulation as no more
than a Spratt in a Whale Belly. The amount bore little Proportion to the Business of the
Country, and [the] People [were] plunged into inexpressible Difficulties.16
The bills of credit in circulation in the several New England colonies, 1703-1751, may
be followed in Table I and, for New England, graphically in Figure I. The effect of these
issues upon the price of silver may be followed in Table II, which gives the annual price
of silver at Boston, and graphically in Figure I. The per capita figures of imports from
England point out the influence of the wartime issues of credit upon trade with the mother
country. During the period, 1702-1706, the annual imports from England averaged 0.71
sterling; in the period, 1707-1715, they averaged 1.15 sterling; and in the period,
1716-1722, they averaged 0.87 sterling.17 The per capita imports from 1707-1715 were
greater than those of any similar period throughout the colonial history of New England.
During the period, 1706-1715, the average annual rate of increase in the price of silver
was 1.70 per cent, while during the subsequent period, 1715-1722, the average annual rate
of increase rose to 6.79 per cent. These figures of per capita imports and of the average
annual increase in the price of silver clearly demonstrate the fact that during the
period, 1706-1715, when silver was available for export to pay the adverse balances
occasioned by the increase in imports from England, the effect upon the price of silver
was but moderate. During the period, 1715-1722, however, the demand for silver continued
strong and silver having grown quite scarce, the merchants were forced to bid one against
another for it to meet their adverse balances, and the price rose much more rapidly.
With the bills of credit annually declining, the Massachusetts gentlemen of business
cast about to find ways of replenishing the circulating medium. One group, taking its cue
from the proposal of Captain John Blackwell circulated in the colony in 1688 and now
reprinted,18 proposed that a group of individuals join together for the purpose of issuing
heir notes in an amount not to exceed 300,000, which they would covenant to receive in
trade, and which were to be lent out "upon good security," real or personal.19
The five directors of the proposed bank were all Boston merchants. The projectors sought
the countenance of the legislature, hoping to obtain an act of incorporation, and to this
end applied to the Assembly in February 1714. The Assembly recognized the need for an
addition to the circulating medium but decided a public rather than a private project was
called for. Since no action was taken at the February session the private projectors
continued to formulate their plans throughout the spring and summer. On 20 August,
however, in response to a memorial from the Attorney General of the province, the Council
restrained the projectors from printing their scheme, putting it on public record, or
emitting any notes or bills until they had laid their proposal before the General
Assembly. This they did at the October session but the Assembly adhered to its earlier
preference for a public issue, and on 4 November authorized a public loan issue of 50,000;
the following day it prohibited any company or partnership from emitting bills of credit
as a medium of exchange or trade without the consent of the legislature. The private
projectors, unwilling to give up the struggle, petitioned the King to incorporate them by
charter. But despite the support of the British merchants trading to New England and of an
initially favorable reception by the Board of Trade, for reasons that do not appear, they
allowed their efforts to languish, and no action was taken by the British authorities.
The struggle between the supporters of a private bank and of a public loan issue has
sometimes been viewed as a struggle between the trading interest, on the one hand, and
agrarian debtors who supported a public issue, on the other. Both projects, however,
appear to have belonged to the trading part of the colony. "A Country-Man" wrote
in the Boston News-Letter in 1720, "that the General Assembly, especially the Country
part[,] had never thought of or consented to it [the public loan], had it not been upon
the great Sollicitation & pressing Importunity of the Trading part."20
The 50,000 issued in 1714 were lent out on landed security to individuals for five
years at an annual interest of five per cent. During the period one-fifth of the principal
was to be repaid annually. The loan issue temporarily restored the circulation and revived
trade. Per capita imports, which had stood at a high of 1.27 in 1711, had dropped to 1.00
in 1714. The next year, however, they rose again to 1.30. By 1716 the circulation had
dwindled again and, since the loan issue of 1714 had appeared so beneficial, a new issue
of 100,000 was thought desirable. The 100,000 in bills of credit in 1716 were to be let
out to borrowers at five per cent annual interest for a period of ten years. The interest
was payable annually and the principal in a lump sum at the end of the period. This time,
however, trade failed to respond to the replenished circulating medium. Per capita imports
had fallen in 1716 to 0.92 and in 1717 they revived to only 0.96. Moreover, when the
increased imports of 1715 came to be paid for a year later, the demand for returns caused
the price of silver to rise from 9 to 10s. the ounce. Henceforth, increasing the
circulation by putting out bills of credit on loan no longer fostered restoration of trade
but only caused the price of silver to rise still further.
Massachusetts neighbor Rhode Island was a small colony "of not a much larger
extent of territory than about thirty miles square . . . of this, a great part is a barren
soil, not worth the expense of cultivation."
The colony hath no staple commodity for exportation, and does not raise provisions
sufficient for its own consumption; yet, the goodness of its harbors [of Newport and
Providence], and its convenient situation for trade, agreeing with the spirit and industry
of the people, hath in some measure supplied the deficiency of its natural produce, and
provided the means of subsistance to its inhabitants.21
By a roundabout trade carried on chiefly with the West Indies, Rhode Island provided
itself with the produce, bills of exchange, and specie necessary to pay for its imports
from England. Few of these imports came from England directly, rather they were imported
through Boston, New York, or Philadelphia. By trade with these several colonies Rhode
Island provided itself with the means of paying for its imports through them.
Rhode Island soon followed Massachusetts example in issuing bills of credit on loan,
putting out its first loan issue in 1715. From that date until 1751 Rhode Island
established nine "land banks" (as her loan offices were called), issuing in
excess of 820,000 in bills of credit. Since, as mentioned above, the bills of one New
England colony enjoyed a circulation in the other New England colonies, Rhode Islands
bills of credit soon flowed to Massachusetts in the course of trade. In order to provide
commodities for her West Indian trade, Rhode Island bought up the produce of
Massachusetts, paying for it with Rhode Island bills of credit. In this way Rhode Island,
so to speak, levied tribute upon Massachusetts, a fact that did not escape the attention
of the keener observers in the latter colony. In fact, John B. MacInnes has written:
"The key to understanding Rhode Islands currency policy up to 1750, is that it was in
fact a parasitical device."22
Unlike Massachusetts, Rhode Island because of her charter was not subject to royal
control through the instrumentality of the royal instructions. As a result, she was free
to multiply her loan issues after Massachusetts had been restrained. In 1720 Rhode Island,
with an eighth of the population of Massachusetts, circulated paper amounting to
one-fourth that of Massachusetts. By 1730, her bills of credit equaled thirty-eight per
cent of those circulating in Massachusetts, although the relative population of the two
colonies had remained unchanged. By 1740, Rhode Islands circulation had grown to one
hundred thirteen per cent of that of Massachusetts, again the relative populations
remaining the same. The outpouring of bills by Rhode Island greatly accelerated the
depreciation of the New England currency.
The depreciating effect of the Rhode Island loan issues upon Massachusetts bills of
credit was such that, when in 1733 Rhode Island emitted 104,000 on loan, a group of
merchants in Boston, fearing that a large part of the issue would gravitate to that city
and depreciate the currency, agreed not to receive the Rhode Island bills and, to meet the
need for a medium, issued their notes on a silver basis. In all 110,000 were issued;
"The Sum put to Interest," it was said, was "very small . . . as the
Undertakers put the Notes away in common Payments, at 22s. per Ounce."23 The notes
were redeemable in silver at 19s. the ounce (which was the price at which silver had
passed at the end of 1731), three-tenths at the end of three years, three-tenths at the
end of six years, and the remaining four-
In 1733, the present value of the merchants notes, calculated at 6% per annum
compounded annually, was such that an ounce of silver should have traded for 27s. 8d. of
the notes. Yet the merchants notes, because they initially passed as a medium of exchange
at par with province bills, were put off at a higher value. Even when silver rose to 23s.
the ounce at the end of 1733, their present value was 17% less than the value at which
they circulated. The merchants soon broke though their resolve not to receive the Rhode
Island bills and by the end of 1734 silver had risen to 27s. at Boston. "As soon as
silver rose to 27s.," Thomas Hutchinson has written, "the notes issued by the
merchants payable at 19s. were hoarded up and no longer answered the purposes of
money."25 By the end of 1734 the value of the notes exceeded that of province bills
by 3.5%; whether this premium was sufficient to cause the notes to be hoarded, as
Hutchinson says, may be questioned. However, when silver reached 27.5s. the ounce at the
end of 1735, the premium rose to 11.7%.26 This was doubtless sufficient to cause at least
a majority of the notes to be hoarded. There are numerous references in the newspapers and
pamphlets of the time to the hoarding of the notes. It appears, however, that not all the
notes were hoarded, but that some were left to circulate at a premium. The Land and Silver
Banks of 1740 need not engage our attention as they soon were suppressed by act of
Parliament and had little economic effect.
Prices. The price of silver, for which quotations exist, serves not only as a measure
of the rise in sterling exchange rates, but also as a rather effective measure of
inflation in New England, as can be empirically demonstrated. In 1707, the price of an
ounce of silver at Boston was 8s.; by 1747, it had risen to 56.8s. Using the 1707 price as
the base, the index number of the price of silver in 1747 is 710. In 1747 two
Massachusetts ministers provided comparisons of a market basket of prices: the first of
1707, the second of 1717, comparing them with the prices of the same articles in 1747. The
market baskets in each case consisted of the provisions necessary to supply the table of a
family for a week. The first basket included a chicken, a goose, a turkey, butter, cheese,
eggs, beef, mutton, pork, veal, corn, rye, wheat, milk, and beer; in addition one finds
candles, a pair of mens shoes, and a pair of women's shoes. If the cost of the goods in
the market basket in 1707 be taken as the base, the index number of the 1747 prices stands
at 741. The second basket included milk, mutton, salt pork, beef, flour, eggs, beer, corn,
rye, turnips, peas and beans, sugar, butter, cheese, candles, and wood. If in this case
the cost of the articles contained in the basket in 1717 be used as the base, the index
number of the 1747 prices stands at 515. The prices of the several commodities in the
baskets did not rise uniformly. In the first basket the 1747 index number for the price of
eggs is 1800, while that of the price of beer, is 450. In the second basket, the 1747
index number for the price of cheese is 741, while that for both eggs and beer is 300.27In
the first basket the 1707 price of a bushel of wheat is 5s., the 1747 price is 25s. If the
1707 price be used as the base, the 1747 index number of the price of wheat stands at 500.
The 1747 index of the Boston price of wheat similarly computed stands at 473.28
Eleven commodities were common to both lists: butter, cheese, candles, eggs, beef,
mutton, pork, corn, rye, milk, and, beer. Using 1707 prices as the base, the index number
of these eleven commodities was: 1707, 100; 1717, 245; and 1747, 881. It was said that the
price of butter rose "the most uniformly of all Provisions." Again using the
1707 price as the base, the index of the butter price was: 1707, 100; 1717, 167; 1733,
450; 1739, 500; and 1747, 1042. Prices rose faster than wages. The laborers on the Boston
Townhouse in 1712 received 5s. a day. By 1739, wages had risen to 12s. a day.29 Using 1712
as the ase, the 1739 index of wages is 240. The 1739 index of the price of butter,
however, was 500.
Perhaps the Massachusetts sterling wheat price ratio gives the best indication of the
rise of commodity prices during this period. The Massachusetts sterling wheat price ratio
is calculated by dividing the price of a bushel of wheat Old Tenor in Massachusetts by the
Pennsylvania sterling price. The effect of such calculation is to smooth out the annual
fluctuations in the price of wheat that derive from the changes in the supply and demand
for wheat during any one year. Massachusetts was a wheat importing colony and Pennsylvania
was a wheat exporting colony. The calculation can be made for the years, 1720-1749. The
wheat price ratio rose from 3.15 in 1720 to 16.53 in 1747, thus the latter figure was 5.42
times the former. The rise in the ratio may be followed in Figure I.30
Sterling exchange rates. In discussing the behavior of sterling exchange rates in New
England during the period, 1703-1750, our inquiry will be centered on the relationship
between the ever-increasing paper circulation and the sustained increase in the sterling
exchange rate. The balance of trade with England was always adverse. Consequently, silver
flowed from New England to the mother country each year. In times of a stable currency,
however, the outflow to England was matched by the inflow from New England's trade with
the West Indies. With the increase of purchasing power that resulted from the increase in
the annual issues of New England's bills of credit, imports from England increased and the
adverse balance increased. As a result, more and more silver flowed each year to the
mother country. At first, when the increases of the bills of credit were relatively
moderate, and when the silver supply remained sizable, the price of silver was not
affected, and the currency retained its value. When the supply of silver became
diminished, however, and not enough silver coins came into the hands of the merchants in
the ordinary course of trade to supply them with the necessary silver for redressing the
adverse balance, they began to bid one against another for it. Thus the price of silver
was bid up and the currency began to depreciate. As the supply of silver in New England
diminished still further, the annual rise in the price of silver increased. By 1720, or in
any event by 1725 or 1726, when the stock became exhausted, the rise in the silver price
became more precipitate. The rise may be followed in Table II, or graphically in Figure I.
By consulting Figure I, one will see that the slope of the currency curve, between 1720
and 1740, is somewhat greater than the slope of the silver price curve during the same
period. In neither case, however, is the curve smooth, although in each case the general
slope remains fairly constant. Without question the chief cause of the rise in the silver
price during this period was the annual increase in the amount of paper currency in
circulation. Since, however, the two curves do not correspond, either in their slopes or
in their fluctuations, other causal elements must be taken into consideration.
The trend in the silver price line in Figure I represents the effects of the increase
in the circulating medium upon the price of sterling exchange. The fluctuations around the
trend represent the effect of accidental changes in the balance of payments from year to
year. As William Douglass wrote:
In New England, as in all other trading Countries, from some particular Accident and
Circumstances, there happened at Times, some small fluctuations in Exchange, without any
Regard to Emissions of Paper Money. At all Times, when Returns in Ship Building, Whale Oil
and Fins, Naval Stores &c. turn out well at Home; Silver and Exchange here suffer a
small fall: at other Times when these prove bad Returns, Silver and Exchange rise a small
Matter; the most noted Instance was in A. 1729, when the usual Returns to Great Britain
turned to bad Account; the Merchants from Home directed their Factors here, to make
Remittances in Silver or Exchange only, and at any Rate . . . Silver rose very
considerably, but after a few Months fell again to the former Price.31
Such accidents account for the fluctuations around the trend. The difference in slope
between the currency curve and the silver price curve must be accounted for otherwise. To
that we now turn attention.
In the absence of the operation of other factors, one might expect the slope of the
silver price trend curve to be the same as that of the currency trend curve. When they
diverge, however, one is forced to look for the cause. Although the increase was not
uniform, trade with England (imports plus exports) tended to rise over the years. If one
calculates a two-year moving average, for trade with England during the two years
preceding the year in question, one has a useful tool for determining the cause of the
difference in the slopes of the currency and silver price curves. Some divergence is
easily accounted for, since some of the increase in currency was absorbed by the growing
volume of trade. To judge whether this explanation alone is sufficient, hypothetical
silver prices were calculated taking both the growth in the money supply and trade into
account.32The calculated silver prices are derived from the quantity theory, using growth
in trade with England as a proxy for growth in trade generally. When the calculated silver
prices have been ascertained, they are then plotted on the silver curve in Figure I. It
will then be seen that the calculated prices fluctuate irregularly about the actual
prices. When the calculated prices are compared with the contemporary evidence respecting
fluctuations in the balance of payments, one will see that they correspond to a marked
degree. In the case of 1729, the year in which, as we have seen, the ordinary returns to
England turned to bad account, the actual price of silver was 20.3s. the ounce, while the
calculated price was 17.87s. the ounce.
The year 1734 provides another example. In that year the act of Parliament that levied
a duty of 6d. per gallon on foreign molasses imported into the colonies first took place.
The act abridg'd the Trade of the Province in one of its most considerable Branches for a
short Time . . . there happen'd also some Failure of its Cod and Whale Fishery, both which
occasion'd a great Deficiency in its Returns that Year, and there was the usual
Importation of English Goods, and no Increase of the Silver and Gold generally imported
into the Province, and of the Bills of Exchange to be purchas'd there, and about the same
Time there happen'd a large Increase of the Paper Currency by a new Emission of
Rhode-Island Bills . . . this Conjunction of Circumstances caus'd Silver to rise from
twenty Shillings to twenty seven Shillings and six pence per Ounce, and consequently the
Bills of Credit to depreciate above one third Part of their former Value.33
On this occasion both the increase in the currency circulation and the deficiency in
returns operated together to raise the price of silver, both the calculated price and the
actual price. In 1733 the actual price of silver had been 22s. the ounce, while the
calculated price had been 23.50s.; in 1734, both prices had risen, the former to 25.70s.,
the latter to 24.90s.; by 1735, however, the actual price had risen to 27.50s., while the
calculated price had risen to only 27s.
Inspection of the currency curve and the silver price curve in Figure 1 will indicate
that the disparity in the slopes of the two curves increases in the years after 1740, the
slope of the currency curve becoming relatively steeper. The formula no longer suffices to
provide an explanation. Consequently, the explanation must be found elsewhere. The annual
rate of increase in the currency curve for the successive periods, 1720-1729, 1730-1739,
and 1740-1749 will serve to emphasize this change in the relationship of the slopes of the
two curves. During 1720-1729, the average annual percentage increase in the currency curve
was 6.2%, that in the silver price curve, 4.8%; during 1730-1739, the figures are: 5.1%
for the currency curve, 3.8% for the silver price curve; during 1740-1749, the figures
are, 16.4% for the currency curve, 7.3% for the silver price curve. The ratios of the
currency curve to the silver price curve in these successive periods are: 1.29, 1.34, and
2.25. How is this increased divergence of the two curves to be explained?
The decade of the 1740's found both England and her colonies engaged in war, at first
with Spain, later with France. In 1739 the War of Jenkins Ear broke out--a war that
continued until 1742. It was fought in the Caribbean. In 1740 a colonial expedition
against Cartagena in Panama was launched. It proved a costly failure. Then in 1744 war
broke out between Britain and France. Soon New England was involved in a life and death
struggle with the French in Canada, a struggle not concluded until 1748. In the summer of
1745 a New England expedition, aided by the British fleet, captured the French stronghold
of Louisbourg on Cape Breton Island. The expedition was a major effort and from the
monetary point of view a costly one. The martial activities during the war accounted for
the great outpouring of bills of credit of the 1740's and the resulting rise in the price
of silver and consequent depreciation of the New England currency. During the 1740's, New
England's imports from England rather diminished than increased. The average imports for
the five years, 1735-1739, were 245,980; for 1740-1744, 195,007; and for 1745-1749,
199,599. Nonetheless, the balance continued adverse. New England, however, was much aided
in meeting her adverse balance by bills of exchange drawn by the several colonial
governors and by military officers in the colony upon the British government. A partial
list of these aids, particulars of which are set forth in Table III, amounts to 634,567
sterling. This sum is equal to 47.2% of New England's unfavorable balance of trade with
England for the years, 1740-1749. These aids, which were ordinarily drawn by bills of
exchange sold to the colonists, provided the funds for easing the strain on the adverse
balance upon New England and, consequently, the price of silver was not bid up to the
point that it otherwise would have been. In this way the increasing disparity in the
slopes of the New England currency curve and the silver price curve is to be explained.
Ordinarily when the balance is unfavorable and it is found necessary to export specie,
the price of exchange rises above the equivalent in silver. In New England during the
period under discussion, however, the silver equivalent was usually higher than the
exchange rate. The exceptions to this were the years, 1700-1710, at the beginning of the
period, and the three years, 1740-1742, towards the close of the period. For the years,
1720-1729, the sterling equivalent averaged 8.9% higher than the exchange rate; for the
years 1730-1739, 13.6% higher; and for the years, 1740-1749, 5.5% higher. Perhaps an
explanation of this reversal in the relationship of the silver equivalent and the exchange
rate is to be found in the following statement of J. Wright:
The Trade of the Northern Colonies continuing for many Years in a ad State, the Balance
with Britain always against them, occasioned the ready Money they had amongst them to be
picked up by the Merchants and Factors residing in America, acting for their Corespondents
or Employers in Britain, and Cash or Bullion, being a certain Remittance preferable to
Bills of Exchange or Produce, which were very precarious, the Bills being often sent back
protested, and the Goods coming to a bad Market; this made the Merchants and Factors rival
each other in purchasing Gold and Silver, and from Time to Time, raised the Price; and in
Proportion as the nominal Value of the same advanced, the Price of Bills, and the Rates of
their Currencies, kept Pace with it, and proportionally depreciated as the nominal Value
of the Specie advanced, compared with the Value of Money in Britain.34
New York and Pennsylvania
Bills of credit before 1750. The currency history of New York and Pennsylvania offers a
sharp contrast to that of New England. Although there was a mild depreciation in the early
years in both colonies as measured by the exchange rate, by the early 1740's the currency
of both colonies had stabilized. The Spanish milled dollar had achieved a customary value
in trade of 8s. in New York and 7s. 6d. in Pennsylvania. Its value was to remain unchanged
throughout the remainder of the colonial period.
The reasons that called forth the first issues of bills of credit in the two colonies
differed. New York, situated on the northern frontier, was more involved in the struggle
with the French in Canada than was Pennsylvania to the southward. In 1709, New York, as a
measure of war finance, emitted her first bills of credit in the sum of 5,000, to be
called in by taxes levied for the purpose. Between 1709 and 1747, New York issued a total
of 206,228 on tax funds. In the year 1737, she also issued 40,000 on loan, making the
total issue through 1747 246,228. From 1702 to 1743 the price of an ounce of silver had
risen from 6s. 10 1/2d. to 9s. 2d. The par of exchange had risen from 125 to 177.77 and
the average annual rate from 133.33 to 174.67. Both the silver price and the exchange rate
indicate a 33 1/3% rise in prices.
The occasion for Pennsylvania's recourse to bills of credit was the depression that
enveloped the colony in the early 1720's. The price of the colony's produce had fallen on
the international market and the resulting unfavorable balance of trade with the mother
country had swept off the silver to England, leaving the colony bereft of a currency.
Trade bade fair to come to a stop. Debtors could not pay their debts and what little
business was left was carried on chiefly by discount, which was essentially barter. The
legislature, after considering recourse to a commodity currency, finally decided, rather
reluctantly, to issue 15,000 in bills of credit on loan. The issue restored economic
activity in the colony but was deemed inadequate, and the next year, 1724, an additional
30,000 was issued on loan. The index of wheat prices (1720 = 100) had fallen to 88.6 in
1724, and during the same period, flour had fallen from 100.0 to 95.0. Immediately
following the issues of 1723 and 1724, both the price of wheat and of flour revived, the
index of wheat to 100.1 in 1724, 125.6 in 1725, and 124.0 in 1726; that of flour to 107.7
in 1724, 129.6 in 1725, and 110.6 in 1726. Although the improvement in the price of wheat
and of flour was widely attributed to the issues of paper currency, it seems to have
resulted entirely from the improvement in the international market, for the index of the
sterling exchange rate (1720 100), which had stood at 101.2 in 1723, in 1724 stood at
100.4. Thus it appears, that no part of the colonial rise in price could be attributed to
an increase in the exchange rate. Trade again subsided in 1729 and a further loan issue of
30,000 was emitted. An issue of 11,110 in 1739 to replace the loan bills of previous
issues that had been retired rounds out Pennsylvania's loan issues. In 1746 she issued
5,000 on tax funds to finance her wartime activities. These were the only Pennsylvania
issues before the French and Indian War. Pennsylvania's issues and the sums in bills of
credit outstanding in each year may be followed in Table IV and graphically in Figure II.
From 1723 to 1743 silver rose from 7s. 5d. to 8s. 6d. the ounce. Exchange likewise rose
from 140.37 to 159.79. The rise in prices that may be attributed to the paper currency is
mild. Measured by the rise in the silver price it was no more than 10.1%; measured by the
rise in exchange, it was 13.8%.
Bills of credit, 1750-1775. The determining event in the currency history of New York
and Pennsylvania in the period after 1750 was the French and Indian War, 1755-1763. Both
colonies found it necessary to emit large sums in bills of credit to finance their wartime
activities. In New York the bills of credit outstanding in November, 1754, amounted to
126,081; by November, 1759, the sum had increased to 489,355, an increase of 288%. In
Pennsylvania the bills outstanding in 1754 amounted to 81,500; by 1760, the sum had
increased to 446,158, an increase of 447%. The sum outstanding annually in New York may be
followed in Table V and graphically in Figure III; those in circulation annually in
Pennsylvania (1750-1775) may likewise be followed in Table VI and graphically in Figure
IV.
The foreign commerce of New Jersey was carried on through the ports of its neighbors,
New York and Pennsylvania. East Jersey imported and exported through the port of New York
and West Jersey through the port of Philadelphia. The demand for imported goods in New
York or Pennsylvania was the New York or Pennsylvania demand plus a portion of the New
Jersey demand. It thus may be that the combined paper circulation of New York plus that of
East Jersey and Pennsylvania plus that of West Jersey may have had more to do with prices
and exchange rates than the circulation of New York and Pennsylvania alone. The population
of East Jersey equaled 46% of the total population of the colony and that of West Jersey,
54%. The paper circulation of New Jersey was divided between New York and Pennsylvania in
these proportions. The combined circulation may be followed in Table VI and graphically in
Figure IV.
In New York, the New York bills of credit in circulation increased by 288% between 1754
and 1759 while the imports increased by 403%. The combined paper circulation of New York
and New Jersey, however, increased by 310% between 1754 and 1759. This figure corresponds
somewhat more closely to the figure for the increase in imports. The remainder of the
increase in imports is perhaps to be explained by the fact that the circulating specie of
the colony had, as a result of funds flowing in to finance the war, increased during the
same period, for as Benjamin Franklin wrote in mid-1756, "New York is growing
immensely rich, by Money brought into it from all Quarters for the Pay and Subsistence of
the Troops."35 In Pennsylvania, the Pennsylvania circulation increased by 447%
between 1754 and 1760, while imports increased by 189%.36 The combined circulation of
Pennsylvania and New Jersey increased by 497%. The fact that the circulation, either joint
or that of Pennsylvania alone, rose by a greater percentage than did imports from Great
Britain suggests that specie also played a role in stimulating imports. On March 8, 1763,
Benjamin Franklin wrote, "The Crown, I am Inform'd, has paid 800,000 Sterling in this
Province only, for Provisions[,] Carriages, and other Necessaries in the Service."37
Prices. Despite the great increase in the paper circulation in the two colonies, the
rise in the indices of wholesale prices was but modest. In New York the index (1765-1766 =
100) stood at 77.3 in 1754; by 1762 it had risen to 106.0, a rise of 37%. In Pennsylvania
the index (1741-1745 = 100) stood at 95.0 in 1754; by 1762 it had risen to 140.1, a rise
of 47%. These modest rises in the wholesale price indices are to be accounted for by the
fact that the commodities that entered into the computation of the indices were
commodities that were traded on the international market, either being imported or
exported. Consequently, their prices were chiefly determined by the conditions that
prevailed on the international market; given the international price, the colonial price
was determined by the exchange rates.
In the foregoing account no mention has been made of the effects, or supposed effects,
of "bookkeeping barter" upon prices and exchange rates. Much of the retail trade
of the colonies, particularly in the country and smaller towns, was carried on by what
William T. Baxter has called "bookkeeping barter."38 Storekeepers prices their
goods in monetary terms, but their customers paid for them in commodities, upon which
prices were likewise placed. When credit was expanding, the demand for the storekeepers'
goods was increased. This increased demand might be expected to raise prices. The supply
of English goods, however, was almost perfectly elastic. Consequently, there was little
pressure on prices from the supply side. The net effect, however, of this increased demand
for English goods was to increase the importation and, consequently, the unfavorable
balance of trade. The expansion of credit doubtless increased the price of domestic
commodities whose supply was not perfectly elastic.
Bills of exchange were always bought and sold for money. The increase in imports that
resulted from the expansion of credit increased the demand for bills of exchange to meet
the increased adverse balance.
Prices generally, however, responded much more to the increase in the currency
circulation. An insight into their behavior is to be found in a letter written by Benjamin
Franklin after his return to Pennsylvania in November, 1762, after a six-year sojourn in
England:
The Expence of Living is greatly advanc'd in my Absence; it is more than double in most
Articles; and in some 'tis treble. This is by some ascrib'd to the scarcity of Labourers
and thence the Dearness of Labour; but I think the [Dearness] of Labour, as well as of
other Things the Labour of which was long since perform'd, or in which Labour is not
concern'd; such as Rent of old Houses, and Value of Lands, which are trebled in the last
Six Years, is in great measure owing to the enormous Plenty of Money among us . . . [There
is now] such an over Proportion of Money to the Demand for a Medium of Trade in these
Countries, that it seems from Plenty to have lost much of its Value.. 39
Prices rose similarly in New Jersey. In the spring of 1763 Governor William Franklin of
New Jersey wrote the Board of Trade: "All the Necessaries of Life in this Country are
encreas'd in Price near Three fold to what they were Seven Years ago."40 Although
direct evidence is lacking, it seems altogether logical that the experience of New York
was similar to that of Pennsylvania and New Jersey.
Sterling exchange rates. The bounds within which sterling exchange rates fluctuated in
New York and Pennsylvania were determined by the fact that in each of the colonies paper
currency, in effect was tied to silver at a given rate. In New York, as has been pointed
out previously, the Spanish milled dollar was rated by custom at 8s.; in Pennsylvania, at
7s. 6d. In England the Spanish milled dollar was worth 4s. 6d. sterling. The ratio between
the sterling valuation and the colonial valuations established the par of exchange in the
colonies. In New York, the par was 177.78; in Pennsylvania, 166.67. This was the colonial
par, and was so viewed in the colonies. In England, however, Spanish silver was a
commodity that was exchanged as other merchandise. Consequently, the price of Spanish
silver varied with the demand and supply. When a colonial merchant exported silver, he
shipped it to a broker in London, who sold it for the best price obtainable. Since this
price varied, the "London" or "effective par" as it may be called for
want of a better name, fluctuated. The par was calculated by dividing the colonial value
of an ounce of Spanish silver by the sterling price of an ounce of silver on the London
market. For example, if, as in New York, the price of silver was 110.625d. the ounce and
the London price was 65d. sterling the London, or the effective par, equaled 170.19. If,
however, the London price was 67d. the ounce, the effective par was 165.11. Thus it was
that, strictly speaking, there was no fixed par of exchange for the currency of New York
and Pennsylvania.
The upper limit of exchange was determined by the London silver price and by the cost
of shipping the silver from the colonies to Britain, a cost that included freight,
insurance, and brokers commission, as well as certain small costs of handling the silver
in London. The lower limit to which exchange might fall was determined by the London
silver price and by the cost of importing silver. The point at which it became profitable
to export silver, or to import silver, was spoken of as the "specie point." At
the outbreak of the French and Indian War, one of the representatives of the British army
in America wrote (1754):
The Ballance of Trade being mostly against our Colonies in favor of Britain, they are
obliged to make a great part of their Remittances in Money or Bills, and the Exchange or
price they give for these Bills, is a good deal Regulated by the price of Silver in London
of which they have Advice by every Ship.41 And when Silver is so dear in London as to bear
the charge of Freight, Insurance, Commission, &c., Exchange falls in America or the
Specie is remitted, but as this is not allwise the Case, they generally chuse good Bills
& give the full Value for them rather than be at the trouble of Remitting the Cash.42
In New York, the cost of shipping specie ranged from 5.34% in peace to 11.20% in war;
in Pennsylvania, from 5.51% in peace to 11.02% in war.43 The range of the percentage
differential between exchange and silver in New York and Pennsylvania for the various
periods may be followed in Table VII. For the years, 1751-1775, the fluctuations in the
exchange rates of New York, Pennsylvania, and Massachusetts, as well as in the market
price of Spanish silver in London as it relates to colonial exchange rates may be followed
in Figure V.
The expanding paper circulation in both New York and Pennsylvania created additional
purchasing power, which in turn stimulated imports from England as the demand for imported
goods increased. In the five years following 1755 imports from England increased markedly
in both New York and Pennsylvania. In New York, imports in 1755 stood at 151,071; in 1759,
they had risen to 630,785, an increase of 318%. In Pennsylvania, imports in 1755 stood at
144,456; in 1760, they had risen to 707,998, an increase of 390%.44 Both increases roughly
paralleled the increase in currency during the same period. The unfavorable balance of
payments of the two colonies with England increased even more than did imports, as exports
to England decreased at the same time that imports were increasing. As a result of the
colonies increased adverse balance with the mother country, the demand for bills of
exchange also increased.
The rise in the demand for bills of exchange to pay for a surplus of imports was more
than offset, however, by the increase in the supply that resulted from the transfer of
British funds to the colonies to aid in the prosecution of the war against France. Despite
the unfavorable balance of trade, the balance of payments was in favor of the colonies.
The result was, that while imports from England were increasing, the exchange rate was
falling. In New York, between December, 1757, and June, 1760, the exchange rate fell from
176.55 to 166.32, a decrease of 9.3%. In Pennsylvania, the exchange rate fell similarly
from 173.33 in June, 1756, to 152.52, a decrease of 12.0%.
By any reckoning the aid provided by British payments in America was substantial in
aiding the colonies to meet their adverse balance of payments. From 1755 to 1760, the
unfavorable balance of New York and Pennsylvania, reckoned at the current values of the
commodities, was 3,412,380,45 while British payments amounted to 2,463,296. This latter
figure is arrived at by adding the payments of the New York deputy for the money
contractors in Britain, the New York and Pennsylvania portion of the cost of victualing
the forces in America during the same years, and the Parliamentary Reimbursements.46 The
British payments equaled 72.2% of the unfavorable balance of trade during the period.
With the fall of Canada that followed the capture of Quebec on September 18, 1759, and
of Montreal on September 8, 1760, the war on the continent came to an end. Thence forward,
British payments in America were drastically curtailed, a fact that was reflected in the
rise in exchange rates in the latter half of 1760. In New York, the exchange rate stood at
166.50 in May, 1760; by December, it had risen to 172.00, and by July, 1761, it had
reached 185.00. There was a similar rise in Pennsylvania. In June, 1760, exchange stood at
155.50; by December, it had risen to 169.50, and by August, 1761, it reached 177.50.
When during 1761 and 1762 the heavy imports of the preceding years had to be paid for,
exchange rose even though the paper circulation of both New York and Pennsylvania was
declining. In New York, between June, 1760, and November, 1762, the paper currency
outstanding fell from 489,355 to 330,807, a fall of 32.4%; in Pennsylvania, the paper
circulation fell from 446,158 in 1760 to 320,676 in 1762, a fall of 28.1%. At the same
time exchange rose in New York from 166.32 to 191.67, a rise of 15.2%; in Pennsylvania the
rise was from 154.46 to 176.07, a rise of 8.5%. This rise in the exchange rate took place
despite the fact that New York and Pennsylvania received continued aid in the form of
British payments, although in a smaller amount as compared with the unfavorable balance
(20.8% as opposed to 72.2% for the preceding period). This fact bears eloquent testimony
to the increased colonial indebtedness resulting from the large imports of late years.47
During these years the silver in both New York and Pennsylvania began to be drained off
to England to aid in the payment of the unfavorable balance. During the period of low
exchange rates, silver remittances to Britain appear to have ceased. The Beekman
Mercantile Papers, which are our principal source for New York, indicate that from 1756
until at least the latter part of 1761, James Beekman shipped no silver to Britain,
although both before and after this period he made frequent shipments.48 In both colonies
the mercantile correspondence of the day complained of the dearth of silver and of its
flight to the mother country. So severe had the drain become by the end of 1763 that on 2
December John Watts, a New York Merchant, wrote to a business associate: "Exchange on
London [at] [1]90 per Ct: the Trade has swept off all Gold & Silver for remittances,
& even given 2 per Ct: Advance, so that we have nothing remaining but Paper
Currancy."49 Thus when New York and Pennsylvania (as well as the other colonies)
entered the period after 1764 with their currency restricted by the provisions of the
Currency Act of 1764, they found themselves with their silver swept off and with a
diminishing paper currency. Moreover, the colonies found their chief source of silver,
trade with the West Indies, curtailed by the new trade laws.
Massachusetts, 1750-1775: A Colony on a Specie Standard
Under the leadership of Thomas Hutchinson, the able speaker of the House of
Representatives, Massachusetts took advantage of the Parliamentary reimbursement of her
expenses in the Louisbourg expedition to retire her bills of credit and return to a specie
standard. By Act of January 26, 1749, it was provided that the Parliamentary money should
be brought over to the colony in Spanish silver coin, which, supplemented by tax funds,
should be used to retire the outstanding bills of credit.50 During the year following
March 31, 1750, the Provincial Treasurer was authorized and directed to pay out the silver
"at the rate of one piece of eight for every 45s. in old tenor and for every 11s. 3d.
in new or middle tenor." To supplement the parliamentary grant a tax of 75,000, new
tenor, was levied to bring in funds sufficient to retire all the outstanding bills of
credit. For the future, the colony was to be on a silver basis. All debts due after March
31, 1750, were to be deemed "payable in coin'd silver only," at rates for the
various tenors in which the debts might be discharged equivalent to those at which the
bills of such tenor might be exchanged for silver at the treasury. New contracts entered
into after March 31, 1750, were understood "to be in silver, at six shillings and
eight pence per ounce" and all pieces of eight of full weight were to be taken at
6s., which, it will be remembered, was the value established by the Proclamation of Queen
Anne.51 The act also provided for the exclusion from circulation in Massachusetts of the
bills of credit of the neighboring New England colonies.
Immediately after the passage of the act, it was transmitted to the provincial agent,
William Bollan, who pressed for its immediate confirmation. This was secured on 28 June
1749. Two weeks earlier, on 16 June, the Parliamentary grant had been paid over to Bollan
and Sir Peter Warren, who, after the acts passage, began to buy silver on behalf of the
province. From the Bank of England and on the open market they purchased 650,000 ounces of
Spanish silver at a net cost of 173,129 sterling. They also purchased nine tons of copper
half-pence and two-farthing pieces at a cost of 2,111 sterling. The remainder of the
Parliamentary grant of 183,649 was consumed by expenses. The money was sacked and boxed
and shipped to New England on H.M.S. Mermaid, Captain Montague, arriving at Boston on
September 18, 1749.52
The redemption of the bills was completed substantially by 12 June 1751. The
stragglers, however, which were received in taxes, were not completely drawn in until
1754. After 1 June of that year Massachusetts was on a specie standard and "to
receive or pay" any of the bills of credit was made an offense subject to a penalty
of 10.53
Massachusetts return to silver and the restraints of the Currency Act of 1751 forced
the colony to rely on another mode of financing her exertions in the French and Indian
War. As a result, the method employed was different from that used in any other colony.
The treasurer was authorized to borrow the sums necessary, at first to finance the
ordinary expenses of government, later to finance the war effort. People initially were
reluctant to lend; but when it was found that the colony redeemed its notes promptly all
reluctance vanished and, as Thomas Hutchinson stated, "the publick security was
preferred to private, and the treasurers notes more sought for than those of any other
person whomsoever."54
"Between 1750 and 1764 there were some fifty odd acts authorizing the treasurer to
issue his certificates. These were issued either to those who would lend or to the public
creditors. They bore interest at six per cent, and no certificate was issued for a sum
less than six pounds."55 The sums issued in each year and the amount outstanding
annually may be followed in Table VIII and graphically in Figure VI. Only a small portion
of the notes were issued in emergencies to the public creditors; the vast proportion were
issued to those who had lent specie to the government. On 1 August 1764 Governor Francis
Bernard wrote to the Board of Trade:
At present [the notes] are allmost wholly in large Sums & kept up as Securities:
and as they're more Valuable than cash, & the rule is in issuing new Notes to prefer
the Creditors upon former Notes, Treasurers Notes are hard to be got & are not at all
circulated. So that the present Currency is wholly Specie, & neither wants nor
receives any assistance from Treasurers Notes.56
So good was the colony's credit that in 1765 it proved possible to refinance at 5%
interest its outstanding indebtedness which carried 6% interest. Thence forward the
outstanding sum in Treasury Notes decreased from year to year until 1774 it stood at
56,170.
Prices. One is left in the dark concerning the effect on the general price level of the
Massachusetts method of financing the French and Indian War. As to wholesale prices, the
only index available is composed of the prices of only three commodities, molasses, rum,
and fish. The index (1765-1766 = 100) rose from 94 in April, 1755, to 155 in January,
1760, a rise of 64.9%. Between January, 1760, and October, 1764, the index fell from 155
to 94, a fall of 39.4%. In the absence of direct evidence one can only conjecture that the
rise in the general price level was much greater, as was also the postwar fall.57
Sterling exchange rates. The sterling exchange rate in Massachusetts fluctuated in
harmony with the rates in New York and Pennsylvania, although the fluctuations were
milder. From June, 1755, to June, 1759, exchange fell from 133.33 to 125.76, a fall of
5.7%. From June, 1759, to December, 1762, exchange rose from 125.76 to 139.50, a rise of
10.9%. The comparable movements in the New York exchange rate were a fall of 9.3% and a
rise of 15.2%; those in Pennsylvania were a fall of 12.0% and a rise of 8.5%. The
sympathetic movement of the exchange rate in Massachusetts, New York, and Pennsylvania
maybe followed in Figure V.58
In the absence of the increase in purchasing power resulting from increased emissions
of paper currency, imports in New England did not rise as rapidly in New England as in New
York and Pennsylvania. In 1755 New England's imports from England amounted, in official
values, to 341,796; by 1760 they had risen to 599,647, a rise of 75.4%; by 1762, however,
they had fallen to 247,385, a fall of 58.7%. The corresponding rises and falls in New York
and Pennsylvania are a rise of 317.5% in New York, followed by a fall of 62.2%; in
Pennsylvania, a rise of 390.1%, followed by a fall of 70.9%.59
From 1755 to 1760, New England's unfavorable balance with England and Scotland amounted
in current values to 8,566,128. It was offset by British payments in America amounting to
1,024,547, payments that amounted to 12.0% of the unfavorable balance. During 1761-1766,
New England's unfavorable balance amounted in current values to 1,016,537.60 It was in
turn offset by British payments amounting to 321,972, payments that amounted to 31.7% of
the unfavorable balance.61
During both periods British payments aided New England materially in meeting her
unfavorable balance, and thus exercised a moderating influence upon exchange rates.
Virginia's Bills of Credit: An Example of Limited Inflation
Virginia was the last of the continental colonies to have recourse to bills of credit,
being forced thereto by the demands of the French and Indian War. The war, which broke out
in territory claimed by Virginia in western Pennsylvania, began disastrously for the
colonists. Beginning in the spring of 1755, Virginia emitted successive issues of bills of
credit that by 1757 had amounted to 207,000. The bills of these issues were made
receivable in the treasury at 5% advance. Early in 1757, however, the colony replaced the
outstanding issues of the preceding years with bills that were made receivable in the
treasury at their face value. The amount of the exchange issue was 99,962. From 1757 to
1762 successive issues totaling 233,000 were emitted, making the total exclusive of the
reissue of 1757, 440,000. Virginia's issues of bills of credit and the amount of bills
outstanding in each year may be followed in Table IX; the amounts outstanding are also
presented graphically in Figure VII.
The fact that the colony was drained of specie in 1755 was impelling cause of the
recourse to bills of credit. Since there was no stock of circulating specie to be
supplanted by the accumulating bills, the potential for depreciation was great.62 The par
of exchange in Virginia was reckoned in the colony at 125. This par seems to have derived
from the fact that the sterling silver crown (worth 5s.) was rated at 6s. 3d. by the
Virginia act of 1727.63 The actual par, however, appears to have been somewhat higher. By
the foregoing act silver was rated at 4d. the pennyweight. The Spanish milled dollar of 17
pennyweight was worth 5s. 6d. This would indicate a par of 129.6.
The effect of Virginia's issues of bills of credit upon her imports from Great Britain
is hard to estimate, for to a great extent her imports depended upon the state of the
tobacco trade. The poor tobacco crops of 1755 and 1758 greatly reduced the tobacco exports
during 1756 and 1759. During the latter years, however, the increased price of tobacco
occasioned by the bad crop made some amends for the crop failure. Despite the decreased
exports of 1756 and 1759, the imports of these years did not suffer. In 1755, the
estimated official value of Virginia's imports was 269,742; by 1760, imports had risen to
542,467, an increase of 101%. This was but a modest increase compared with those of
Pennsylvania and New York, where during the same period imports of the former colony rose
by 385% and those of the latter by 223%.64 From this comparison we can perhaps conclude
that the role of bills of credit in Virginia in stimulating increased imports was not as
great as in Pennsylvania and New York.
Sterling exchange rates. While in New York exchange rates fell by 9.3% between 1756 and
1760 and in Pennsylvania fell by 12% between 1756 and 1759, in Virginia exchange rose from
an annual average of 130.42 in 1755 to an annual average of 163.41 in 1764, a rise of
25.3%. As we have seen the rise in exchange in New York and Pennsylvania came after the
secession of the war on the continent in 1760. In New York between 1760 and 1764 exchange
rose 15.3%, while in Pennsylvania during the same period, it rose 8.5%. Although exchange
in Virginia suffered a sustained rise between 1755 and 1764, the major rise came in the
period between 1759 and 1764, the rise during that period amounting to 16%, as against a
rise of only 8% between 1755 and 1760.
The rise in the sterling exchange rate was accompanied by an increase in the rate at
which the Spanish milled dollar circulated in the colony. The dollar was legally rated at
5s. 10d. and customarily passed in trade at this figure; however, by 1764 the rate had
increased to 6s. 8d., an increase of 14.3%, over the legal price, a figure nearly as great
as the 16% rise in the exchange rate during the same period.65
Virginia, like the other colonies, was aided in meeting her adverse balance by the
British payments in America. Between 1757 and 1762, these payments in Virginia amounted to
320,271 sterling. The adverse balance between 1755 and 1761 amounted to 110,647; thus the
British payments amounted to 289.5% of the unfavorable balance.66
The fact that the major rise in the Virginia exchange rate occurred after the cessation
of British aid payments suggests that the aids played a material part in damping the rise
in the exchange rate between 1755 and 1760.
Joseph Albert Ernst places great emphasis upon the ebb and flow of British credit sales
in the colonies to explain the fluctuations in the exchange rate. British exports to
colonies were usually sold on a years credit, although frequently it was two, or even
three, years before they were paid for. Obviously, until colonial importers paid for their
importations they little influenced the demand for bills of exchange. In Virginia,
particularly, some planters habitually drew upon their London correspondent bills of
exchange in anticipation of future tobacco consignments. Shipments frequently failed to
materialize as expected and thus the planter became in arrears to his British
correspondent and sometimes the arrears grew from year to year. Thus during the period
British credit financed colonial importations. Ernst argues that in times of financial
crisis in Britain, such as those that developed in 1763 and again in 1772, British
merchants dunned their American debtors in an effort to call in their outstanding American
credits. Assuming that they were successful in collecting their outstanding debts, the
result was that the demand for bills of exchange was increased and the rate of exchange
bid up.67
For many reasons, the validity of this explanation appears doubtful. It was one thing
to dun the Virginia planter, it was quite another to collect what was due from him. The
planters assets were in land and slaves, and only when he sold his tobacco crop did his
assets become liquid. Thus he could not raise money to pay his debts unless he sold his
tobacco and, more important, had tobacco to sell. Again, even if the planter were in a
position to pay his debts, there was the matter of effecting the transfer of the money to
Britain. Bills of exchange were in limited supply, particularly during the period of high
exchange in the early 1760's. As the Pennsylvania provincial secretary, James Logan, once
wrote to William Penn, when the proprietor was pressing him o transmit the proprietary
revenues, "We cannot coin bills [of exchange]."68
Even if the debtor was prepared to make a remittance, he often faced difficulty in
finding a good bill of exchange, or, indeed, in finding any bill at all. This is
illustrated by the New York merchant John Watts who on 6 November 1764 wrote to General
Moncton, "I did intend to send a Bill of Exchange but we cannot draw & the Money
Agents say they do not."69 If the planter entered the market, he would, of course,
even when silver was unavailable, tend to bid up the price of exchange. But there were
limits to the rate of exchange that he would pay for bills, thus his demand was
effectively limited. Moreover, Maryland's economic fortunes ran with those of her
neighbor, Virginia. Maryland also produced tobacco and sold it in Britain. It seems
altogether likely that when Virginia experienced an unseasonable year, Maryland's crop
suffered as well. During and after 1763 there was no disturbance of Maryland exchange such
as occurred in Virginia. Moreover, during the financial crisis of 1772, which was even
more severe than that of 1763, although the Virginia exchange rate rose by a modest
amount, no immoderate rise occurred such as in the early 1760's. Again, disturbances in
the other colonies exchange rates did not compare to Virginia. All of this strongly
supports the view that the Virginia issues of bills of credit mainly caused the French and
Indian War rise of Virginia exchange rates.
It has sometimes been urged that Virginia's accumulating indebtedness to Britain, which
by 1755 amounted to 1,356,123 sterling, supports this view. At first blush, the
indebtedness of Virginia looks formidable; however, when it is reduced to a per capita
basis using the white population for the purpose, it appears less so. The per capita
indebtedness was 4.98 sterling. In Maryland, where the white population was less than half
that of Virginia, the debt of 304,385 was less than a quarter that of Virginia; the per
capita indebtedness was 2.27. Virginia's per capita indebtedness was below that of South
Carolina, which amounted to 5.64. The highest per capita indebtedness was that of Georgia,
which amounted to 6.83. Neither in Maryland nor in South Carolina nor in Georgia were
there disturbances in the exchange rate following the financial panic of 1763 that by any
measure equaled those in Virginia. Of course the accumulating indebtedness, as long as it
remained outstanding, took pressure from the exchange market and effectively canceled out
an equivalent in imports. In the Middle and Northern colonies the per capita indebtedness
was small, ranging from .0042 in New Jersey to .49 in New York. Here it could scarcely
have had a significant effect upon exchange rates.
All things considered, Virginia's paper issues appear to have played the dominant role
in the determination of exchange rates. Without the paper circulation exchange would not
have risen to the height that it did. Only when the bills of credit slipped the tether
that bound them to the customary value of silver, was exchange free to rise to the height
that it did.
Summary
In our survey we have seen that accumulating issues of bills of credit created
purchasing power. Where, as was the case in the colonies, manufactured goods were imported
from England, part of this purchasing power was spent for manufactured goods; this in turn
increased imports and accentuated the unfavorable balance of trade with England. Part of
the increased purchasing power was spent for colonial products and tended to bid up their
price directly. When it came time to meet the increased adverse balance with the mother
country, silver began to be exported to supplement the bills of exchange that were
available. As long as sufficient silver came into the hands of the merchants in the
ordinary course of trade to enable them to meet their needs for silver to make
remittances, the price of silver and the price of exchange did not rise. As soon, however,
as the accumulated stock of silver was reduced to the point that merchants who needed
silver to make remittances to another country were forced to bid for it one against
another, the price of both silver and exchange rose. As the silver supply was exhausted,
increases in the bills of credit in circulation caused proportional increases in the price
of silver and bills of exchange, unless the increased volume of trade, by absorbing the
circulating medium, retarded the rise.
In New York and Pennsylvania, where custom had rated the Spanish milled dollar at 8s.
and 7s. 6d., respectively, the ratio of the colonial value of the dollar to the sterling
value determined the colonial par of exchange. The effective par, however, fluctuated with
the London price of silver, being determined by the London price and the silver content of
the dollar. Under such conditions, fluctuations in the exchange rate were confined to the
distance between the specie points, which, in turn, varied with the cost of shipping
silver. Since these costs, particularly insurance, were greater in time of war, the
exchange rate fluctuated considerably.
The basic cause of this fluctuation was the same as that in New England during the
early years of the century. An increased circulation of bills of credit created purchasing
power and led to increased imports from Britain. When these imports were paid for, the
demand for bills of exchange increased and the price was bid up. If, however, Britain at
the same time was transferring funds to America to finance the war, the additional supply
of bills of credit arising from this source might not only keep the exchange rate from
rising, but induce it to fall. But when the transfer of British funds ceased and the full
force of the demand for bills of exchange occasioned by the increased imports was
released, exchange rose.
The internal price level, however, bore no relation to the increase in the exchange
rate, or to the increases of the price of those commodities that were imported or
exported. Internal prices rose to two or three times their prewar level.
In a colony where a specie standard prevailed and bills of credit were not issued as
war finance measures, as was the case in Massachusetts between 1750 and 1775, the price of
exchange fluctuated in harmony with that in New York and Pennsylvania, but the
fluctuations were not so great. In all probability internal prices rose to a considerable
degree, although in the absence of direct evidence one cannot say how they compared with
internal prices in New York and Pennsylvania.
Virginia presents a complex and difficult case. Her trade with the mother country was
direct and her economic fortunes were linked to the prosperity of the tobacco trade.
Although fluctuations in the value of the colony's imports and exports from year to year
influenced the exchange rate, it is probable that, all things considered, it was the
substantial issues of bills of credit to finance the colony's contribution to the French
and Indian War, that played the dominant role in causing Virginia's exchange to break
loose from silver and fluctuate more widely than that of either Massachusetts, New York,
or Pennsylvania.
The exchange rate of Massachusetts, New York, and Pennsylvania fluctuated in harmony as
is evident from Figure V. That of Virginia also, to a degree at least, fluctuated in
harmony. During the French and Indian War the agents of the money contractors sold bills
of exchange in all of the above colonies as long as they could be sold for silver or gold.
When Virginia's specie supply was exhausted, contractors bills were no longer sold there;
as a result, exchange rose more than in the other colonies.
One final conclusion emerges clearly: the quantity theory of money is, indeed, useful
in analyzing currency practices, prices, and sterling exchange rates, not only where
runaway inflation is the issue, as Ernst contends, but where it is not.
Endnotes
1. [Editor's note] Robert Craig West, "Money in the Colonial
American Economy," Economic Inquiry, 16 [1978] 1-15; Bruce Smith, "American
Colonial Monetary Regimes: The Failure of the Quantity Theory and Some Evidence in Favor
of an Alternate View," The Canadian Journal of Economics, 18 [1985] 531-64; and
"Some Colonial Evidence on Two Theories of Money: Maryland and the Carolinas,"
Journal of Political Economy, 93 [1985] 1178-1211; Elmus Wicker, "Colonial Monetary
Standards Contrasted: Evidence from the Seven Years War," Journal of Economic
History, 45 [1985] 869-84. Ron Michener, "Fixed Exchange Rates and the Quantity
Theory in Colonial America," Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy,
27 [1987] 233-308; Michael D. Bordo and Ivan A. Marcotte, "Purchasing Power Parity in
Colonial America: Some Evidence for South Carolina 1732-1774: A Comment," ibid.,
311-23; and Bennett T. McCallum, Monetary Economics, Theory and Policy, New York, 1987;
and "Money and Prices in Colonial America: A New Test of Competing Theories,"
Journal of Political Economy, 100 [1992] 143-61.
2. [Editor's note] The connection between the original and revised
estimates for Pennsylvania is subtle, and involves a matter generally overlooked by those
using colonial money supply estimates. Ideally, one would like to know how much currency
was in the hands of the public. This is not known. What generally exists are the dates and
quantities of currency authorized by colonial assemblies, and the dates and quantities of
currency burned. Most data series are for the total authorized, minus the total burned,
which only approximates currency in the hands of the public. A time lag existed between
the authorization and the printing and expenditure of currency, and another between the
time currency passed for the final time into the treasury and its destruction. Also,
currency might pass through the colonial treasury several times between its initial
issuance and final destruction. Whatever sum was being held by either the treasurer or
land bank commissioners was out of the hands of the public. In Pennsylvania, the
legislature noted the sums and dates of its expenditures of newly authorized money. In the
table presented here, Brock used expenditures instead of authorizations to construct his
estimates, better approximating the ideal series.
3. The Alderman Library at the University of Virginia houses Brock's
draft chapters, research notes, and collection of primary and secondary source material.
Brock's draft chapters are available on microfilm by writing the manuscript department and
requesting "Brock #10715, Manuscript for a book on currency."
4. The Boston Evening Post of October 25, 1773 estimated the peacetime
cost of shipping specie to London at 6% : 2.5% for insurance and brokerage, 2.5% for
commissions, and 1% for freight.
5. Appendix to William Graham Sumner, A History of American Currency,
(New York, 1968), 362.
6. Henry Thornton, An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper
Credit of Great Britain, edited by F.A. Hayek and Augustus Kelley (New York, 1978) 159,
244, 248, 259.
7. Money and Politics in America, 1755-1775, (Chapel Hill, 1973), 5-7;
"Colonial Currency: A Modest Inquiry into the Uses of the Easy Chair and the Meaning
of the Colonial System of Freely Floating International Exchange," Explorations in
Entrepreneurial History, 2nd Ser., 6 [1969] 187-197.
8. Andrew McFarland Davis, ed., "Some Considerations Upon the
Several sorts of Banks Propos'd as a Medium of Trade," [1716] Colonial Currency
Reprints (Boston, 1910, 1964), 1:336.
9. Leslie V. Brock, The Currency of the American Colonies, 1700-1764,
(New York, 1975), 18.
10. Arthur H. Cole, Wholesale Commodity Prices in the United States,
1700-1861,(Cambridge, Mass., 1938), wherein the components of the several price indices
are set forth. Their inadequacy as a measure of the general level of prices will be
demonstrated below.
11. Despite Ernst's statement to the contrary, the author and Ernst have
never been at variance on this point.
Ernst wrote: "In holding rigidly to the quantity theory [of money]
and trying to show how monetary policy influenced overall price levels, historians have
tended to ignore the other forces at work at the time and to overlook the seasonal,
short-run, and cyclical nature of colonial prices. On the other hand they have also
generally failed to take into account the effect on exchange rates of swings in the volume
of British loans to America, shifts in British wartime expenditures in the colonies, and
changes in the colonies terms of trade and volume of trade. The most important example [of
this] is Brock, Currency of the American Colonies,"Ernst, Money and Politics, 6-7.
Ernst, in the paragraph quoted, scarcely does justice to the views
expressed by in Currency of the American Colonies, where many of the forces that Ernst
mentions that affect the price of foreign exchange are discussed by Brock in his Colonial
Currency. One may consult pages 58, 62-63, and 352.
12. William Douglass, "A Discourse Concerning the Currencies of the
British Plantations in America," [1740] Colonial Currency Reprints, 3:320.
13. Brock, Colonial Currency of the American Colonies, 23.
14. Ibid., 30.
15. Ibid., 29-30; Jonathan Belcher, "A brief Account of the Rise,
Progress and present State of the Bills of Credit in New England," 1740, CO 5/ 881
part 2, ff. 199-204.
16. Ibid., 25-26. The Mather quotation is from Mather to Sir Peter King,
December 22, 1714.
17. The corresponding per capita unfavorable balances of trade (imports
minus exports) were: 0.38; 0.78; 0.48.
18. "A Model For Erecting a Bank of Credit: With a Discourse in
Explanation thereof," [London, 1688] Colonial Currency Reprints, 1:153-187;
[Reprinted at Boston, 1714] ibid., 209-237.
19. "A Projection for Erecting a Bank of Credit in Boston. Founded
on Land Security," [Boston, 1714] ibid., 319-333.
20. "The Country-Man's Answer, to a Letter Intitled, The Distressed
State of the Town of Boston Considered," [from the Boston News-Letter, 18 April 1720]
ibid., 409-412.
21. Records of the Colony of Rhode Island and Providence Plantation in
New England, 1707-1740, John Russell Bartlett, ed., (Providence, 1859) 4:379.
22. John B. MacInnes, "Rhode Island Bills of Public Credit,
1710-1755," (unpubl. Ph.D. diss., Brown University, 1952). MacInness is the most
comprehensive study we have of the Rhode Island currency.
23. "Scheme or Articles upon which the Merchants and Others have
Acted, who are now giving out their Notes of Hand," Andrew McFarland Davis, "The
Merchants Notes of 1733," Mass. Hist. Soc., Proceedings, 2nd Ser., 17 [1903] 204-8;
The New-England Weekly Journal, 1 April 1734.
24. Thomas Hutchinson, The History of the Colony and Province of
Massachusetts-Bay,(Cambridge, Mass., [Mayo Edition] 1956) 2:289.
25. Ibid.
26. [Editor's note] This paragraph has been rewritten slightly for
clarity. Brock's handwritten notes, and his discussion in Draft of an Unfinished
Manuscript for a Book on Currency in Colonial America, "Massachusetts
1730-1741," (Alderman Library) 34-36, leave no doubt about Brock's intended meaning.
The premia mentioned in the text are theoretical, based on Brock's present value
calculations. No actual citations are available for the market value of merchants notes
for these dates. However, contemporaries remarked that once the merchants notes ceased to
circulate as a medium of exchange they were valued according to their present value. Brock
compared the citations that have survived, from 1737-41, and found they correspond closely
with the value predicted by his calculations. Sources: Hugh Vance, "Some Observations
on the Scheme," [1738] Colonial Currency Reprints, 3:209; Richard Fry "Scheme
for a Paper Currency," [1739] ibid., 3:270; William Douglass, "Discourse,"
[1740] ibid., 3:348; "Postscript to a Discourse," [1741] ibid., 4:50; "A
Letter to a Merchant in London," [1741] ibid., 4:71.
27. Boston Evening Post, 13 June 1747; Boston Gazette, 8 December 1747.
28. Arthur H. Cole, ed., Wholesale Commodity Prices in the United
States, 117.
29. William Douglass, "Discourse," Colonial Currency Reprints,
3:328-9.
30. Brock, Colonial Currency of the American Colonies, 595.
Wheat Price Ratio.
Wheat was a commodity, the price of which fluctuated greatly from year
to year, even with a stable currency, because the crop coming to market varied as a result
of the weather, infestations of "the fly" and "the rust," and
plantings, and also because it was the staple export commodity in the chief producing
colonies. Thus its domestic price was determined by the supply, the demand at home and
abroad, and the prevailing exchange rate.
To relate changes in the price of wheat as a result of a sustained
depreciation of the domestic currency (inflation), it is necessary to iron out
fluctuations in price resulting from the factors indicated above.
Pennsylvania was the chief colonial producer and exporter of wheat,
flour, and bread. New England, on net balance, imported wheat, Massachusetts being the
chief importer. One can correct the Pennsylvania price for the depreciation its currency
underwent, as measured by the exchange rate, and also for the annual fluctuations in the
exchange rate from non-monetary factors, by dividing the Philadelphia price by the
sterling exchange rate, thus obtaining the sterling price. If the Boston price in Old
Tenor is divided by the Philadelphia sterling price, the result is a ratio that reflects,
rather accurately, the effect of the sustained depreciation of the Massachusetts (and New
England) currency during the years for which the ratio can be computed, 1720-1749. Of
course, the ratio does not iron out the effect upon the Massachusetts exchange rate and
price of silver resulting from non-monetary causes, such as the sudden rise in 1729, and
the fall in 1730, when "the usual Returns to Great Britain turned to bad
Account" in 1729, but recovered in 1730.
One should note the extent to which the Wheat Ratio line parallels the
Silver Price and Bills of credit lines on the graph.
32. This and the next sentence is added by the editor as a substitute
for a lengthy discussion by Brock where, using a complicated and confusing formulation, he
argued against the idea that the silver price was equal to the volume of the money supply
divided by the volume of trade. For the text see the original manuscript, Alderman
Library.
33. "An Enquiry Into the State of the Bills of Credit Of the
Province of the Massachusetts-Bay in New England: in a Letter from a Gentleman in Boston
to a Merchant in London," [Boston, 1743-44] Colonial Currency Reprints, 4:195-196.
34. J. Wright, The American Negotiator: or the Various Currencies of the
British Colonies in America, (London, 1761) vii. The Massachusetts exchange rates are to
be found in John J. McCusker, Money and Exchange in Europe and America, 1600-1775. A
Handbook (Chapel Hill, 1978) 140-141. The silver equivalent at the market price of silver
in London is to be found in McCusker, 151-152. The McCusker compilation is a magnificent
monument to the application of diligence and competence to a very difficult field. It is
an indispensable tool for anyone working in the field of American colonial currency. Gaps
in the McCusker compilation of the market price of silver in London for the early years of
the 18th century have been filled in from K. N. Chauduri, "Treasure and Trade
Balance: The East India Company's Export Trade, 1660-1720," Economic History Review,
2nd Ser., 21:500.
35. Benjamin Franklin to William Parsons, 28 June 1756. The Papers of
Benjamin Franklin, Leonard Larabee, ed., (New Haven, 1965--) 6:465-466.
36. [Editor's note] The percentage increase in New York imports
originally given in the MSS was 503%, and for Pennsylvania, 520%. Since there were reasons
for suspecting an error, I revised them, using Jacob Prices "New Time Series for
Scotland's and Britain's Trade with the Thirteen Colonies and States, 1740-1791,"
William and Mary Quarterly, 3d ser., 32 [1975] 322-25.
37. Benjamin Franklin to Richard Jackson, 8 March 1763, Franklin Papers,
10:209.
38. W. T. Baxter, The House of Hancock, (New York, 1965) 17-21.
39. Benjamin Franklin to Richard Jackson, 8 March 1763, Franklin Papers,
10:209.
40. New Jersey Archives, 1st Ser., 9:384.
41. Italics added.
42. Stanley Pargellis, ed., Military Affairs in North America,
1748-1765, (New York & London, 1936) 41.
43. [Editor's note] These numbers come from Table VII, and were revised
along with Table VII.
44. Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to
1970,(Washington, D.C., 1975) part 2, 1176.
45. "The New York Merchants proved to their General Assembly in
1764, from original invoices from Great Britain, that for the three preceding years they
had imported what they were charged 1,500,000 for, while the . . . Custom House account
for those 3 years makes it no more than 1,042,024, and . . . the Merchants of Pennsylvania
at the same time and on the same occasion [for repealing the Stamp Act] proved their
imports from Great Britain . . . for the said 3 years to be about 1,500,000 also, when the
[Custom House] account of exports makes it no more than 925,544 . . ." Thus it
appears that the current value of imports was approximately one-half greater than the
official values; hence, the unfavorable balances of trade of both New York and
Pennsylvania have been multiplied by 1.5 to obtain the current value. Benjamin Franklin to
the London Chronicle, 3 November 1768, Franklin Papers, 15:253.
46. Money contractors payments, 1,522,199, New York and Pennsylvania
portion victualing costs, 847,873, Parliamentary reimbursements, 93,224--total, 2,463,296.
The portion of the victualing cost allocated to New York and Pennsylvania was the same as
the proportion that the New York money contractors payment bore to the total money
contractors payment in America (70.2%). Money Contractors Declared Accounts, A.O.
1/190-582; Account of Sir William Baker for Victualling the Army in North America, Aug.
16, 1756--March 25, 1760 [actually 1765]; Account of John Thomlinson and John Hanbury,
Contractors for providing Money for the Subsistance and Payment of the Land Forces sent
from Great Britain and Ireland to Virginia and other parts of North America, 24 December
1754--27 May 1757, T. 1/377, f. 153; 39 George II., c. 29; T. 52/501, 287-291; 33 George
II., c. 18.
47. The British payments, 1761-1762, consisted of the following: New
York money contractors payments, 340,904 sterling, Pennsylvania money contractors
payments, 260,000 sterling, a total of 600,904 sterling; New York and Pennsylvania's
proportion of the cost of victualing the British forces in North America, 168,963
sterling; Parliamentary reimbursements, 112,847--882,714 sterling. Money Contractors
Declared Accounts, A.O. 1/190-582; Account of Sir William Baker for Victualling the Army
in North America, Aug. 16, 1756--March 25, 1760 [actually 1765]; Parliamentary
reimbursements, 29 George II., c. 29; 31 George II., c. 33; T. 52/50, 287-291, T. 52/51,
244. Pennsylvania Votes and Proceedings, 7:5915.
48. Beekman Mercantile Papers (New York, 1956), 2:534, 539, 544, 567,
577, 580, 581, 739, 825-6, 901, 905-6.
49. To Gedney Clarke, "Letter Book of John Watts, 1762-1765,"
New York Hist. Soc., Collections, 61:204-205.
50. Acts and Resolves of the Province of Massachusetts Bay, 3 [1878]
430-41.
51. Brock, Colonial Currency of the American Colonies, 252-253.
52. Ibid., 254-255.
53. Acts and Resolves of Massachusetts Bay, 3:717-719.
54. Hutchinson, History, 3:7.
55. Brock, Colonial Currency of the American Colonies, 273.
56. C.O. 323/19.
57. [Editor's note] Winifred B. Rothenberg, "A Price Index for
Rural Massachusetts, 1750-1855," Journal of Economic History, 39 [1979] 983, table 2,
reveals considerable yearly fluctuations in prices received by farmers, but no striking
trend in this period. If anything, prices are somewhat higher in the post-war years than
during the war.
58. [Editor's note]
Correlations for Series in Figure VNew York exchange rate on
LondonPennsylvania exchange rate on LondonMassachusetts exchange rate on
LondonPennsylvania exchange rate on London.927Massachusetts exchange rate on
London.606.547Par of Exchange.330.321.021
59. Historical Statistics of the United States, part 2, 1176. Separate
import and export figures for Massachusetts are not available. In all probability,
however, fluctuations in Massachusetts imports from England corresponded to the
fluctuations in New England's imports. British expenditures in Massachusetts increased the
monetary circulation and, as a result, increased purchasing power that doubtless led to
increased imports from England. Imports from England were chiefly introduced into New
England through Massachusetts or, to some degree, through New York. Connecticut, which
emitted sizable issues of bills of credit during the French and Indian War, was not
engaged in direct trade with England. During the period, Rhode Islands sizable issues of
bills of credit underwent rapid depreciation that eroded away their purchasing power and
thus canceled out any influence they may otherwise have had on imports. The new tenor
issues of New Hampshire emitted from 1755 to 1757 underwent depreciation with similar
effects. The New Hampshire sterling bills of credit emitted from 1758 to 1762 appear,
however, to have maintained their value.
60. [Editor's note] I cannot determine the source of the estimate of the
unfavorable balance of trade of New England, and the numbers given are quite different
from other estimates. For example, using Jacob Prices data, and without multiplying by
1.5, gives a figure for 1755-60 of 2,496,120, and for 1761-6 of 1,643,586. See "New
Time Series for Scotland's and Britain's Trade," William and Mary Quarterly, 3d ser.,
32 [1975] 322-25.
61. The official value of the unfavorable balance was transformed into
current values by multiplying it by 1.5.
British payments, 1755-1760, consisted of money contractor payments,
667,346 (.40 x 1,668,365), victualing payments, 144,936 (.12 x 1,207,796), Parliamentary
reimbursements, 212,265--total 1,024,547 sterling. Money Contractors Declared Accounts,
A.O. 1/190-582; Account of Sir William Baker for Victualling the Army in North America,
Aug. 16, 1756--March 25, 1760 (actually 1765); Account of John Thomlinson and John
Hanbury, Contractors for providing Money for the Subsistance and Payment of the Land
Forces sent from Great Britain and Ireland to Virginia and other parts of North America,
Dec. 24, 1754--May 27, 1757, T. 1/377, F. 153; Parliamentary reimbursements, 29 George
II., c. 29; 31 George II., c. 33; T. 52/50, 287-291; T. 52/51, 244.
The British payments, 1761-1762, consisted of money contractors
payments, 56,537 (.40 x 141,343), victualing payments, 84,908 (.076 x 1,117,207),
Parliamentary reimbursements, 180,527--total 321,972. Money Contractors Declared Accounts,
A. O. 1/190-582; Account of Sir William Baker for Victualling the Army in North America,
Aug. 16, 1756--March 25, 1760 (actually 1765); Parliamentary reimbursements, 29 George
II., c. 29; T. 52/50, 287-291; T. 52/51, 244.
62. [Editor's note] If there was "no stock of circulating
specie" in the colony for the paper to supplant, as Brock says, why did a huge
percentage increase in the supply of money result in only modest inflation? I disagree
with Brock's statement, and feel that he could have made better use of Virginia's
experience to establish his principle thesis: that offsetting specie flows helped keep
inflation within bounds.
Even without paper money, the stock of circulating specie in Virginia
was highly variable, fluctuating in response to the state of the tobacco market. This we
know from John Hemphill's excellent study Virginia and the English Commercial System,
1689-1733, (New York, 1985). John Mairs Book-keeping Methodiz'd (3d edition) describes
Virginia in the late 1740's as abundantly supplied with circulating specie. Yet on the eve
of the French and Indian War, and before any paper money was emitted, Francis Jerdone
wrote that "the gold & silver which was current in the country a few years ago is
now chiefly vanished." A partial answer as to why there was not more inflation is
that the stock of specie in Virginia was not chronically small, but rather had been at a
low ebb when emissions of paper money began. The people of Virginia were willing to hold
more money at the existing price level, and had paper not been supplied, would probably
have managed their affairs so as to acquire more specie.
At the beginning of the French and Indian war, specie, though scarcer
than it had been a few years earlier, still circulated. As Virginia issued paper money,
her remaining specie disappeared. Corbin wrote in 1762 that "upon the . . . large
Emission in 1757 almost the whole Species of Gold and Silver which was in the Colony
disappeared and Exchange kept rising." The problem would continue, Corbin maintained,
as long as the quantity of money issued continued to "exceed the Demands of
Trade." This was a commonly held view in colonial Virginia. Even those who attributed
the disappearance of specie to the vagaries of trade admitted that people often blamed
paper money because of the close coincidence in timing. In January 1759, Francis Fauquier
commented that in the seven months since his arrival in Virginia, all the specie he had
seen, gathered together in a heap, would not amount to 100 sterling. Burnaby, who visited
in the summer of 1759, blamed paper money, and said there was "not a pistole or a
dollar remaining."
Sources: Francis Jerdone to Capt. Hugh Crawford, 12 September 1754,
William and Mary Quarterly, 3d ser., 14 [1957] 144-45; Richard Corbin's memorial (1762) to
the Lord Commissioners of the Treasury, CO 5/1330, 256; Rinds Virginia Gazette, 26 April
1770; Purdie and Dixon's Virginia Gazette, 4 December 1766; Francis Fauquier to the Lords
of Trade, 5 January 1759, CO 5/ 1329, 169; Rev. Andrew Burnaby, Travels through the Middle
Settlements in North America in the years 1759 and 1760, [1775, 2d edition] (reprint,
Ithaca, N. Y., 1968) 29.
63. William Waller Hening, Statues of Virginia, 4:218-220 (1 George II.,
c. 9).
64. [Editor's note] Suspecting an error, I replaced the original trade
figures for New York (318%) and Pennsylvania (365%) with numbers derived from Prices
"New Time Series for Scotland's and Britain's Trade." Brock's construction of
the Virginia trade figures is described in a later endnote.
65. The Papers of George Washington, "Ledger A," Library of
Congress.
66. Calculation of the sterling value of Virginia exports.
From the 2s./hhd. duty &c. on tobacco exports, it is possible to
calculate the number of hogsheads of tobacco exported annually for the year ending October
25. The revenues produced by the 2s.hhd./ duty &c. included revenues other than those
arising from the 2s. duty. Thus, it is necessary to adjust the gross figure of hogsheads
exported derived by dividing the gross revenue by 2s. It is possible to do this because
for the years 1745 to 1756 we have the figures for annual exports from another source, and
likewise, for the years 1769 and 1770. If the average of the annual exports from the
independent source be divided by the average of those for the corresponding years
calculated from the revenues of the 2s./hhd., the result will be .8284. The gross
calculation of the annual hogsheads exported is then multiplied by .8284 to obtain the
adjusted calculation. This will be found, on the average, to be accurate within .99 of 1%.
Assuming 1,000 pounds to be the weight of a hogshead, the value of the annual export in
Virginia currency is then calculated. The prices used were obtained from the ledgers of
Edward Dixon, in the Library of Congress. Dixon was a Port Royal, Virginia, merchant. The
ledgers covered the years, 1743-1774. The value of the annual exports in Virginia currency
thus obtained was reduced to sterling by dividing it by the average annual exchange rate
expressed as a decimal. The average annual exchange rate was calculated from monthly
quotations collected by the author and by John J. McCusker.
The official value of British tobacco imports was calculated by
multiplying the number of pounds imported into England by 2 1/4d. and the number imported
into Scotland by 2 1/2d. The figures for tobacco imports were obtained from Jacob M.
Price, France and the Chesapeake (Ann Arbor, 1973) 2:844. The annual official value of
British tobacco imports from Virginia was subtracted from the official value of all
imports to obtain the value of British imports from Virginia other than tobacco. To this
figure was then added the current sterling value of Virginia tobacco exports to Britain to
give the total value of Virginia exports to Britain. Since the official value of British
exports to Virginia and imports from Virginia is not available, the figures being given
for Virginia and Maryland jointly, Virginia was apportioned two-thirds of the joint
exports and imports. To the figures for imports from Britain was added the current value
of the imports of slaves. The number of slaves imported annually was obtained from
Historical Statistics of the United States, 2:1172; the price of slaves imported was
obtained from ibid., 1174. The annual imports from, and exports to, Britain from Virginia
are to be found in William and Mary Quarterly, 3d Ser., 32 [1975] 322-325. Virginia's
unfavorable balance of trade for the years, 1755-1761, was then calculated.
The total British aids for the same period was then calculated. These
consisted of sums transferred by the money contractors in 1757 and the Parliamentary
reimbursements for the years, 1758-1762.
67. Ernst, Money and Politics, 7, 356.
68. Correspondence Between William Penn and James Logan, 1700-1750,
[March 1755] (Philadelphia, 1870) 1:368.
69. Letter Book of John Watts, 1762-1765, New York Hist. Soc.
Collections, 61 [1911] 308.
Send e-mail to lisa@studyworld.com
with questions or comments about this web site.